ContentslistsavailableatScienceDirect
JournalofCorporateFinance
journalhomepage:www.elsevier.com/locate/jcorpfin
Corporategovernance,externalmarketdisciplineandfirmproductivity
GloriaY.Tiana,GarryTwiteb,⁎
abSchoolofBankingandFinance,AustralianSchoolofBusiness,UniversityofNewSouthWales,Sydney,NSW2052,AustraliaSchoolofFinance,ActuarialStudiesandAppliedStatistics,AustralianNationalUniversity,Canberra,ACT0200,Australia
articleinfoabstract
UsingasampleofAustraliancompaniesoverthe2000–2005period,weexaminetheimpactofinternalcorporategovernanceonfirm'stotalfactorproductivity,takingintoaccounttheinteractionbetweeninternalgovernanceandexternalmarketdiscipline.Ourempiricalfindingspointtoasubstitutioneffectbetweenproductmarketcompetitivenessandfirm-levelcorporategovernance.Overall,internalcorporategovernancemechanisms–moreefficientboardsandgreaterCEOstock-basedcompensation–areeffectiveinstrumentsforimprovingfirmproductivity.However,internalgovernanceislesseffectivewhenafirmfacesahighlycompetitiveproductmarket.Wefindonlyweakempiricalsupportforanassociationbetweenfirm'sownershipstructureandproductivity,andnosupportforanassociationbetweenindustrytakeoverintensityandfirmproductivity.
©2010ElsevierB.V.Allrightsreserved.
Articlehistory:
Received26July2009
Receivedinrevisedform23November2010Accepted13December2010
Availableonline16December2010JELclassification:G30
Keywords:
Firmproductivity
CorporategovernanceExternalmarketdiscipline
“Productivityisn'teverything,butinthelongrunitisalmosteverything.”–PaulKrugman,1990,TheAgeofDiminishedExpectations
1.Introduction
Doesafirm'schoiceofinternalcorporategovernancemeasuresinfluencefirmperformance?Therehasbeenagrowingempiricalliteratureonthelinkbetweencorporategovernanceandfirmperformance.Thispaperbuildsonthisliteraturebyconsideringthedifferentialeffectofinternalcorporategovernanceonfirmperformance,takingintoaccounttheinfluenceofexternalmarketdisciplinefacedbythefirm(intermsofproductmarketcompetitivenessandanactivemarketforcorporatecontrol).Incontrasttotheexistingliterature,wemeasurefirmperformanceusingtotalfactorproductivity(TFPhenceforth).1Productivity,definedastheresidualproductionoutputbeyondandabovethecontributionofinputcosts,isarguablyabettermeasureofthefirm'srealeconomicperformance.Giventhatpriorliteraturehasestablishedthatgoodinternalgovernanceisrelatedtobetterfinancialprofitabilityandhighermarketvaluation,2onewouldexpectthatgoodgovernancealsohasapositiveimpactontheunderlyingdeterminantoffirmvalue,namely,productivity.Theprimarypurposeofthisstudyistofillinthisgapinourknowledge,toaddresswhethergoodinternalgovernanceindeedhelpsimprovefirmproductivity.
⁎Correspondingauthor.SchoolofFinanceandAppliedStatistics,AustralianNationalUniversity,CanberraACT0200,Australia.Tel.:+61261259190;fax:+61261250087.
E-mailaddresses:y.tian@unsw.edu.au(G.Y.Tian),garry.twite@anu.edu.au(G.Twite).1TheexceptionsareHillandSnell(1989),PaliaandLichtenberg(1999),andBarthetal.(2005)whoutilizedtotalfactorproductivityinconsideringtheinfluenceofownershipstructureonfirmperformance.Totalfactorproductivityhasbeenusedelsewheretoconsidertheimpactofleverage(KimandMaksimovic,1990)andbankruptcy(MaksimovicandPhillips,1996)onfirmperformance.2Forexample,JensenandMurphy(1990),HartzellandStarks(2003)andCoreetal.(1999).0929-1199/$–seefrontmatter©2010ElsevierB.V.Allrightsreserved.doi:10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2010.12.004
404G.Y.Tian,G.Twite/JournalofCorporateFinance17(2011)403–417
Further,wedrawuponanotherstrandofliteraturethatdocumentsalinkbetweenindustry-widecompetitivenessandfirm-levelinternalcorporategovernanceinstruments,suchasmanagerialincentiveschemes(AggarwalandSamwick,1999),businesscombinationlaws(GiroudandMueller,2010)andanti-takeoverprovisions(Chouetal.,2008).Weexplicitlyexaminewhetherthedegreeofexternalmarketdisciplineaffectsthelinkbetweeninternalgovernanceandfirmproductivity.
Australia,liketheUS,isacommonlawcountrywithawelldevelopedcapitalmarket,albeitsmaller.TheconventionalwisdomisthustoclassifyAustraliaashavingan“outsidersystem”,similartothatevidencedintheUS.However,Australia'scorporategovernanceismorerepresentativeofan“insidersystem”(DignmaandGalanis,2004).Firstly,shareholdingsinAustraliaaremoreconcentrated,withmanycorporationshavinglargeblockholders(LaPortaetal.,1999;LambaandStapledon,2003).Inoursample,theaveragefirmhasanownershipconcentrationratioof35%(measuredascommonstocksheldbyinsiders).Secondly,executivecompensationinAustraliaislesstiedtostockperformance.Inoursample,theCEOofanaveragefirmreceivesonly6%oftotalpayinsharesorstockoptionswhile73%remunerationintheformsoffixedsalaryorcashbonus.Thirdly,AustraliancorporateboardshavealongtraditionofseparatingtherolesofchairmanandtheCEO.Furthermore,giventhattheAustralianequitymarketisrelativelysmallandcorporateownershipisconcentrated,itisnotalwaysfeasible(orsensible)tohavecompleteboardindependence.Inoursample,theaverageAustraliancorporateboardhas5to6directors,withmajoritybeingnon-executivedirectors.WhilstAustraliancompaniesfaceproductmarketcompetitionthatiscomparabletotheirUScounterparts,takeovers(inparticularhostilebids)arelesscommonintheAustralianmarket.3Insum,theseinstitutionaldifferencessuggestthatAustraliarepresentsasanideallaboratorytoexaminetheinfluenceofinternalcorporategovernanceandexternalmarketdisciplineoncorporateproductivity.
Inthefirstpartofourempiricalanalyses,wedefineandcalculateTFPforasampleofAustraliancompaniesovertheperiodof2000to2005.Inthesecondpart,weexaminehowTFPisimpactedbyvariouselementsofinternalcorporategovernance(boardcharacteristics,ownershipstructure,andCEOcompensation),differentproxiesofexternalmarketdiscipline(productmarketcompetitionandtakeoverthreat)andtheirinteractions.
Ourmainfindingisthatinternalcorporategovernancematters,buttheextentdependsontheexternalmarketenvironment.Overallinternalcorporategovernanceisaneffectiveinstrumenttoimprovefirmproductivity.FirmswithmoreefficientboardsandhigherCEOstock-basedcompensationhavehigherproductivitythanotherwise.However,internalgovernanceislesseffectivewhenafirmfacesacompetitiveproductmarket.Thereisastrongsubstitutioneffectbetweeninternalgovernanceandexternalcompetition.Further,wefindonlyweaksupportforarelationshipbetweenownershipstructureandproductivity.Ourresultsarerobusttovariousmodelspecificationsandcontrollingforanumberoffirm-levelfactorsandfixedeffects.4Insummary,ourfindingsareconsistentwiththeargument,datingbacktoatleastAlchian(1950)andStigler(1958),forasubstitutioneffectbetweeninternalcorporategovernanceandexternalmarketdiscipline,measuredasthelevelofindustry-widecompetition.However,wefindnoassociationbetweenthelevelofindustry-leveltakeoverintensityandtheeffectivenessofinternalgovernance.
Thisstudyaddstotheexistingliteratureinseveralways.Firstly,beyondownershipstructurethathasbeenexaminedinexistingstudiesconcerningtherelationshipbetweencorporategovernanceandfirmproductivity,weexaminetherolesplayedbyboardsandmanagerialincentivecontracts.Ourfindingsindicatethatboardstructureisofparticularimportance.Secondly,wetest,explicitly,theimportanceofexternalmarketdisciplineandhowitinteractswithinternalgovernanceindeterminingfirmproductivity.Weprovideempiricalevidenceinsupportoftheargumentthatproductmarketcompetitionservesasasubstituteforinternalgovernance.Wecontrolforunobservablefirmheterogeneity,thereforeensuringtherobustnessofourresults.Finally,thisstudyisthefirsttointegratecorporategovernanceandproductivityliteratureinthecontextoftheinstitutionaldifferencesintheAustralianenvironment,complementingpriorstudiesthatfocusprimarilyontheU.S.corporateenvironment.
Therestofthepaperisorganizedasfollows.Section2reviewsrelevantliteratureandsummarizeskeytestablehypotheses.Section3describesthedataandpresentsdescriptivestatistics.Section4outlinesourempiricalframework,presentsthemainfindingsanddiscussesrobustnesschecks.WeconcludewithSection5.2.Relatedliteratureandtestablehypotheses
Ourpaperisrelatedtoseveralstrandsofexistingliterature—measuringfirmperformancebasedonproductivity,theroleofinternalcorporategovernanceinenhancingfirmperformance,andhowexternalmarketdisciplineimpactstherelationshipbetweenthefirm'sinternalgovernanceandfirmperformance.
Productivityrepresentsimprovedefficiencyinafirm'seconomicperformance,aftertakingintoaccountthecontributionofinputcosts.Ithaslongbeenrecognizedineconomicsthattotalfactorproductivityisasignificantcomponentofeconomicgrowthatthefirmlevel.5However,isfirmproductivityrelatedtofirmvalue?PaliaandLichtenberg(1999)findapositivecorrelationbetweentotalfactorproductivityandfirmvalue(measuredasTobin'sQ).Whilstgoodinternalgovernancehasbeenfoundtoenhancefirmvalue,itremainstoconsidertheimpactofinternalgovernanceandexternalmarketdisciplineonfirmproductivity.
Duringtheperiodof2000to2005,theUSmarketwasfarmoreactivethattheAustralianmarket,withthenumberoftenderoffersintheUSmarketrepresenting167%ofthetotalnumberoflistedfirms,whereasisAustraliathenumberoftenderoffersrepresentedonly74%ofthetotalnumberoflistedfirms.4Ananalysisofthelinkbetweenfirmproductivityandcorporategovernancedoesraiseendogeneityconcerns.Inparticular,biasesintroducedbytheeffectofunobservedfirmcharacteristicsarearealpossibility.Whileestimatingfixedeffectspanelregressionspotentiallyaddressesthisissue,oneshouldinterprettheseresultswithsomecaution.5Forasummaryoftheliteraturelinkingeconomicgrowthandtotalfactorproductivitybothatthefirmandeconomywidelevel,seeHulten(2000).
3G.Y.Tian,G.Twite/JournalofCorporateFinance17(2011)403–417405
2.1.Relationshipbetweeninternalcorporategovernanceandfirmperformance
Ingeneral,empiricalstudiesmeasurethelevelofinternalgovernancealongfourdimensions:boardcharacteristics,ownershipstructure,managerialcompensationandshareholderrights.
Researchersineconomics,managementandfinancehavelongbeenanalyzingtheimportanceofownershipstructure.Forinstance,ShleiferandVishny(1986)arguethatblockholdershaveboththeabilityandincentivetomonitorcorporatemanagers,thusreducingagencycostsandenhancingfirmperformance.Morcketal.(1988)andMcConnellandServaes(1990),amongothers,identifyacurvilinearrelationshipbetweenTobin'sQandthefractionofcommonsharesownedbycorporateinsiders.Firmperformancemayalsobeaffectedbyvariouscharacteristicsoftheboardofdirectors.Alongthisline,manystudiesfindthatfirmperformanceisnegativelyrelatedtoboardsizeandthatnon-executivedirectorsalsopositivelyaffectfirmvaluation,whileotherspresentcontradictingevidence.Forinstance,Jensen(1993)arguesthatsmallerboards,beingabletoexercisecontrolmoreeffectively,shouldhaveapositiveimpactonfirmvalue.Yermack(1996)andConyonandPeck(1998)havepresentedevidencethatfirmswithsmallerboardshavehigherTobin'sQ.However,Colesetal.(2008)challengethesearguments,andfindthatcomplexfirmshavelargerboardswithmoreoutsidedirectors,andtheperformanceofcomplexfirmsindeedincreaseinboardsize.Borokhovichetal.(1996)findthatboardindependencecanaddfirmvalue,whileBhagatandBolton(2008)reportnegativerelationbetweenfirmperformanceandproportionofoutsidedirectors.Athirdaspectofinternalgovernancehastodowithmanagerialcompensation.InordertoalignaCEO'sownintereststothoseofshareholders,theoptimalcontractshouldhavetheCEO'scompensationpackagelinkedtofirmperformance.Stock-basedcompensationsuchasrestrictedsharesandstockoptionsarepaidtotheCEO(andothertopmanagers)toimprovefirmperformance,potentiallythroughenhancedproductionefficiency(e.g.Coreetal.,1999;andMurphy,1999).Lastbutcertainlynottheleast,agrowingnumberofstudieshaveexaminedvariouscomposite-indexmeasuresofgovernance.Forinstance,Gompersetal.(2003)constructedtheGIMindexbasedon24anti-takeoverprovisions,whileBebchuketal.(2009)createdanentrenchmentindexbasedononly6oftheseprovisions.Bothstudieshavedocumentedapositiverelationbetweeninternalgovernance(asproxiedbytherespectiveindex)andfirmperformance.
Whenstudyingtheimportanceofinternalcorporategovernancetofirmperformance,theexistingliteraturehasfocusedprimarilyonfinancialmeasuressuchasaccountingratesofreturnandstockmarketvaluation.Literatureonhowcorporategovernanceinfluencesfirmproductivityismuchlessextensive.HillandSnell(1989),examining122Fortune500firms,proposethatownershipstructureinfluencesproductivitybothdirectlyandindirectlythroughdiversification,R&Dandcapitalintensity.PaliaandLichtenberg(1999)findthatmanagerialownershipchangesarepositivelyrelatedtochangesinproductivity,basedonasampleofU.S.manufacturingfirms.UtilizingapanelofNorwegianfirms,Barthetal.(2005)documentanegativerelationshipbetweenfamilyownershipandfirmproductivity,inparticularwhenafamily-ownedfirmismanagedbyafamilymember.Ontheotherhand,KokeandRenneboog(2005)findthat,inpoorlyperformingUKfirms,thepresenceofadominantoutsideshareholderhasasignificantpositiveimpactonfirmproductivity.Martikainenetal.(2009)findthat,forasampleofS&P500firms,thosecontrolledbyfamiliesaremoreproductive.Theyattributethisdifferencetothehigherproductiveefficiencyoffamilyfirms.
Withrespecttothepotentialimpactonproductivity,verylittleattentionhasbeengiventowhetherotheraspectsofinternalcorporategovernancebeyondownershipstructure–inparticularboardcharacteristicsandmanagerialcompensation6–alsoinfluencefirmproductivity.Giventhisgapinourknowledge,ananalysisofvariouselementsofgovernancefromthepointofviewofproductivityshouldprovideadditionalinsightsonthebenefitsofinternalcorporategovernance.2.2.Roleofexternalmarketdiscipline
Ithaslongbeenarguedthatproductmarketcompetitionhelpsimprovefirmperformance,andservesasapowerfultooltoresolveconflictsbetweenshareholdersandmanagers(e.g.Alchian,1950;Stigler,1958).Hart(1983),ShleiferandVishny(1997)andAllenandGale(2000)allpositthatmoreproductmarketcompetitioncouldbeaneffectivemechanismtoreducemanagerialslackorinefficiency.7Insupportoftheseconjectures,Nickell(1996)findsthatthefirm'smarketpowerisrelatedtolowerproductivity,withgreaterindustry-levelcompetitionassociatedwithhighergrowthinfirm-levelproductivity.AggarwalandSamwick(1999)findthatmorecompetitiveindustriesarecharacterizedbyweakerpay-for-performanceincentives.Chouetal.(2008)documentthatfirmswithweakergovernancestructurestendtobeincompetitiveindustriesortheyhavelowmarketpower.Further,governancehasasignificantimpactonfirm'sstockmarketreturnsonlywhenproductmarketcompetitionisweak.GiroudandMueller(2009)findthattheimpactofgoodinternalgovernance,asmeasuredbytheGIM-index,onfirmperformanceissmallandinsignificantincompetitiveindustries,whilelargeandsignificantinnon-competitiveindustries.GiroudandMueller(2010)investigatehowfirmsincompetitiveandnon-competitiveindustriesperformdifferentlyafterthepassageofbusinesscombinationlaws,whichreducesthetakeoverthreatandinturnweakensfirminternalgovernance.Theirpaperdocumentsthat,onlyinnon-competitiveindustries,doessuchweakenedinternalgovernancecoincideswithsignificantlyworsenedfirm-leveloperatingperformance.
Analternativemeasureoftheexternalmarketdisciplineiswhetherafirmfacesanactivemarketforcorporatecontrol.However,thedirectionoftheassociationbetweentheleveloftakeoverthreatandfirmperformanceisunclear.WhilstMasulisetal.(2007)
AnexceptiontothisisBulanetal.(2007),whoreportapositiverelationshipbetweenfirmproductivityandCEOpay-performancesensitivityfromstockoptions.7Notallagreewithpostulateofapositiverelationshipbetweenproductmarketcompetitionandfirmproductivity.Analternativetheoreticalviewisinfavorofanegativerelationship.Forinstance,inmorecompetitiveenvironment,firmsfacegreatermarketuncertaintyandmorevolatilecashflows,sotheyarelesswillingtoinvest,whichinturnharmsfirmproductivity(e.g.Levinetal.,1985).Nickell(1996)providesabalancedviewonthisdebate.
6406G.Y.Tian,G.Twite/JournalofCorporateFinance17(2011)403–417
Table1
Summarystatistics—productivityestimates.Thistablepresentssummarystatisticsforourproductivitymeasures.PanelApresentsthemean,median,standarddeviation,minimum,maximum,andnumberofobservationsforeachvariable—output,labourandcapitalinputcosts,totalfactorproductivity(TFP)estimatedwithsectorfixed-effect,andlabourproductivityisthelogarithmoutputperemployee.PanelBpresentstheoveralltime-constantinputfactorloadingsintheestimationofTFP,togetherwithtime-constantfactorloadingsforfourindustrysectors—mining(energy),manufacturing,servicesandtrade.VariablesareasdefinedinAppendixA.
PanelA:output,inputcostsandTFPVariablename
Output($mil)Labour($mil)Capital($mil)
Totalfactorproductivity(TFP)Labourproductivity
PanelB:TFPinputcostfactorloadingsInputfactorloadings
Overall
Labour($mil)Capital($mil)
0.2810.719
Energy0.2620.738
Manuf.0.2690.731
Services0.4480.552
Trade0.3510.649
OBS23062306230623061362
MEAN511.7383.87353.942.489.79
MEDIAN267.5332.56137.752.339.67
STDDEV2450.95367.662247.32
2.996.85
MIN0.020.000.01−12.20
0.12
MAX37917.763665.1032246.17
14.9225.25
arguethathighertakeoverthreatshouldberelatedtobetterfirm'sfinancialperformance,anumberofotherpapers(e.g.ShleiferandVishny,1986;Stein,1988)predictthatlowerlikelihoodoftakeoverthreatincreasesfirm'sproductivity.Thus,theusefulnessofmarketforcorporatecontrolinpromotingbetterperformanceisanempiricalmatter.
Insupportofapositiverelationshipbetweentheleveloftakeoverthreatandfirm'sproductivity,LichtenbergandSiegel(1987)findthattheleastproductiveplantsaremostlikelytothetargetofatakeoverandthattakeoverstendtobeassociatedwithincreasedproductivity.Inasimilarvein,BertrandandMullainathan(2003)investigatehowfirmproductivitychangesafterthepassageofbusinesscombinationlaws,whichreducesthelikelihoodofatakeoverthreat.Theydocumentthatbusinesscombinationlawscoincidewithlowertotalfactorproductivity.
Buildingonexistingtheoriesandempiricalstudiesdiscussedabove,wetestthefollowingspecifichypothesesinthisstudy.H1.Betterinternalcorporategovernancereducesagencyproblemsandincentivizesmanagerstoimprovefirmproductivity.H2.Externalmarketdisciplineactsasasubstituteforinternalcorporategovernance.Therefore,thepositivelinkbetweengovernanceandfirmproductivityisweakerinmoredisciplinedindustries(morecompetitiveproductmarket,ormoreactivetakeovermarket)thanotherwise.3.Dataanddescriptivestatistics
Ourdatacomefromvarioussources.Westartwithalistof1080companiesinConnect4Boardroomdatabaseovertheperiodof2000to2005.Usingthislist,weobtaindetailedexecutiveanddirectorstatusandcompensationdata,whichwethenusetogeneratefirm-levelcorporategovernancemeasuresconcerningCEOcompensationandboardcharacteristics.OurprimaryownershipdatasourceisWorldScope,fromwhichweobtainthetime-varyingownershipconcentrationratio.FinancialdataaresourcedfrombothBvD'sORBISdatabaseandAspectHuntleydatabase.Weexcludefirmsinthefinancialindustry,duetotheirdifferentreportingstructures,andfirmswithlessthan2yearsofconsecutivefinancialdata.Ourfinalsampleincludes2306firm-yearobservationscovering543differentAustraliancompaniesovertheperiodof2000–2005.3.1.Measuringtotalfactorproductivity(TFP)
Weestimateafirm'sTFPinspiritsimilartothatinotherexistingstudies(suchasPaliaandLichtenberg,1999;Bulanetal.,2007).TFPistypicallyusedintheliteratureasameasureoftechnologyadvanceorenhancedefficiencyinproduction.WeuseaversionofCobb–DouglasproductionfunctiontoderiveTFP,intwosteps.First,weestimatethetime-invariantinputfactorloadingsinapanelsetting,assumingthatfactorloadingsarethesameforallfirmswithinaparticularindustrysector.WethencalculateTFPforeachfirmineachyearastheresidualbetweenactualoutputandtheestimatedoutputusingthetime-constantfactorloadings.Theestimationprocedureisasfollows:
LβK
Yit=Ait×Lβit−1×Kit−1
→yit=ait+βLlit−1+βKkit−1+εitsubjectto:βL+βK=1
ˆˆait=yit−βLlit−1+βKkit−1
ð1Þ
ð2Þ
G.Y.Tian,G.Twite/JournalofCorporateFinance17(2011)403–417407
whereYistheoutput,ListhecostsoflabourandKisthecostofphysicalcapitalinput.Lower-caselettersrepresentlogarithmofthesevariables,andat,logarithmA(technologyorefficiency),istermedasTFP.Outputismeasuredusingoperatingrevenue,labourinputusingcostsofemployees,andcapitalinputusingnetproperty,plantandequipment(PP&E).8ThesevariablesaresourcedfromORBISdatabase.Becausedifferentindustrystructuresmightaffecttherelativeimportanceoftheinputvariables,wealsoincludeafixedeffecttoaccountforsector-levelheterogeneityinthefirststep.Theindustrysectorsweconsideraremanufacturing,services,utilitiesandmining(energy),andtradeandtransportation.Finally,wetrimpotentialoutliersat1%and99%.
Table1reportsdescriptivestatisticsoffirmoutput,inputcosts,andtheTFP.Weobservethat,onaverage,capitalaccountsformorethantwo-thirdsinputcostsinproduction.Theaverageoperatingrevenueofoursamplefirmsis$512million,averagelabourcostsof$8millionandcapitalcostsof$354million.Overallinputfactorloadingsforlabourandcapitalare0.281and0.719respectively,andtheaverage(median)TFPestimatedwithsector-fixed-effectis2.48(2.33).Asexpected,therearesomedifferencesacrosssectors:forinstance,theimportanceofcapitalismoreobviousformanufacturersandenergycompanies,whilelabouriscriticalforfirmsinservicefirms.TheseestimatesaresomewhatdifferentthanthoseofPaliaandLichtenberg(1999),whoestimatedproductionfunctionsforasampleofU.S.manufacturerbetween1983and1992,alsousinglabourandcapitalinputs.93.2.Internalcorporategovernanceandexternalmarketdiscipline
Wemeasurecorporategovernancealongoneofthreedimensions:boardcharacteristics,ownershipstructure,orCEOcompensation.10Onthedimensionofboardcharacteristics,ourprimarymeasureisNEDS,whichistheproportionofnon-executivedirectorssittingonaboard.Onthedimensionofownershipstructure,ourprimarymeasureisownershipconcentrationratio(COhenceforth),thepercentagecommonequityheldbyinsidersasagroup,asreportedinWorldscopedatabase.OnthedimensionofCEOcompensation,ourprimaryvariableisCEO_STKPAY,thelogarithmtransformationofdollarvalueCEOstock-basedcompensation.Wepositthatinsiderownershipprovidesincentivesforexecutivestooperatetheircompaniesmoreefficiently,thatmoreindependentboardisbetteratmonitoringtopmanagers,andthatstock-basedcompensation(inparticularstockoptions)incentivizestheCEOtoimprovefirmproductionefficiency.Insummary,weexpectapositiverelationshipbetweenTFPandmeasuresofgoodinternalcorporategovernance.
Externalmarketdisciplineismeasuredalongoneoftwodimensions:productmarketcompetitiveness(COMPETITIONhenceforth),ormarketforcorporatecontrol(MKTCONTROLhenceforth).Toassessthecompetitivenessofproductmarket,wefirstconstructtheHerfindahl-Hirschmanindexusingfirmsalesorassets(HHIhenceforth),basedon4-digitGICScodes.11AlowerHHIindicatesstrongerproductmarketcompetition,orlessconcentrationofmarketpowerheldbylargeplayerswithintheindustry.WethenrankallindustriesbasedontheirHHIscores,andsetthebinaryindicatorCOMPETITIONtooneifafirmoperatesinanindustrywhoseHHIisinbottomtercileinaparticularyear,andzeroforthosefirmsinthetoptercile.Toassesswhethermarketforcorporatecontrolimposescrediblethreattotheexistingmanagers,wefirstconstructindustry-widetakeoverratio(M&Ahenceforth),definedasthenumberofbothcompleteandincompletemergersandhostiletakeoversdividedbythenumberofactivefirmsineachindustry.12AhigherM&Aimpliesmoreactivemarketforcorporatecontrolandagreatertakeoverthreat.ThebinaryindicatorMKTCONTROListhussettobeoneifafirmoperatesinanindustrywhoseM&Ainaparticularyearisinthetoptercile,andzeroforthosefirmsthatareinthebottomtercile.13Wepositthattougherexternalmarketenvironment(i.e.morecompetitiveproductmarket,orgreatertakeoverthreat)wouldforceafirmtooperatemoreefficiently,leadingtobetterproductionefficiency.WethusexpectapositiverelationshipbetweenTFPandindicatorsofexternalmarketdiscipline.Inaddition,ifexternalmarketservesasasubstituteforefficientinternalcorporategovernance,weexpecttofindinternalgovernancehavinglessimpactonTFPinthepresenceofgreatermarketdiscipline.
Intheempiricalregressionmodelstofollow,wealsoconsiderasetoffirm-levelcontrolvariablesthatmayinfluencefirmproductivity.Inparticular,weconsider:ROA,financialprofitabilitymeasuredasreturnonassets;SIZE,logarithmoffirm'stotalassetsplusone;AGE,logarithmofnumberofyearssincefirm'sincorporation;GROWTH,themarket-to-bookratioofcommonequity;and
ThisdefinitionofTFPisconsistentwiththelabourproductivityliterature.Forrobustnesschecks,wealsotestalternativespecificationsofTFP.Forinstance,wealsoconsiderthecostofmaterialsasanadditionalinput.The3-factorTFPmeasurehasacorrelationof0.828withthe2-factorTFPreportedinthepaper,andourregressionresultsremainqualitativelythesameusingthisalternativemeasure.9InPaliaandLichtenberg(1999),Table2,inputshareofone-yearlaggedlabourisonaverage0.697andtheinputshareofone-yearlaggedcapitalisaround0.119.Thereareseveralfactorsthatcontributetothedifferencebetweentheirandourestimates:(i)mostimportantly,thetwostudiesutilizedifferenttimeperiods/countrysettings,(ii)givendatalimitation,wemeasurelabourinputbyitsdollarcostratherthanthenumberofemployees,whichisthevariableusedinthepriorstudy;and(iii)weseparatetheestimationofinputfactorloadingsfromananalysisofwhataffectsTFP.Inparticular,inour1st-stepinputfactorloadingequation,weassumetime-invariantestimatesinsteadofcontrollingforyearfixedeffects.However,weincludeyearfixedeffectsinthe2nd-stepregressionanalysiswhenweinvestigatetheseparateimpactsofcorporategovernanceandproductmarketcompetitiononTFP.10Therearecurrentlynoequivalents,inAustralia,ofGompersetal.(2003)anti-takeoverindexortheBebchuketal.(2009)entrenchmentindex.11GiroudandMueller(2010)definedHHIbasedon3-digitSICcodes.BecauseAustraliaisarelativelysmalleconomywithbigplayersinsomeindustries,suchdetailedsegmentation–165differentindustriesat3-digitSIClevel–isnotfeasibleforoursample.Excludingthefinancialsector,wehave20(9)industrygroupsbasedon4-digt(2-digt)GICScodes.Atabledetailingthe4-digitGICSindustryclassificationandassociatedHHIscoresispresentedinAppendixB.12Incompletetakeoverscouldalsorepresentrealthreattoincumbentmanagement.Wealsoconsideredonlycompletedmergersandacquisitions,andtheresultsarequalitativelythesame.Inaddition,duetothelowfrequencyofM&Aeventsthroughoutoursampleperiod,thetakeoverratiosaredefinedat2-digitGICSindustrylevel.13Effectively,wereduceoursamplesizebyaboutonethird.Inrobustnesstestsnottabulatedforbrevity,wealsoredefinethesetwoindicators(i)oneifafirmoperatesinanindustrywhoseHHIscoreorM&Aratioisinbottomtercileinaparticularyear,andzerootherwise;and(ii)basedonmedianHHIscoresandmedianM&Aratios,thusincludingallsamplefirms.Theresultsarequalitativelythesameasthosereportedinthepaper.
8408G.Y.Tian,G.Twite/JournalofCorporateFinance17(2011)403–417
Table2
Summarystatistics—keyvariables.Thistablepresentssummarystatisticsofkeyvariablesforthesample,whichincludes543Australiancompaniesovertheperiodof2000–2005.PanelApresentsthemean,median,standarddeviation,minimum,maximum,andnumberofobservationsforeachvariable.PanelBpresentsthePearsoncorrelationsforeachpairofvariables.Thekeyvariablesinclude:Productivity—TFP;Internalcorporategovernance—OWN_PCT,BODSIZE,NEDS,CEO_STKPAY,andCEO_INCENT;Externalmarketdiscipline—HHI_sales,HHI_asset,andM&A;Firmlevelcontrolvariablesare:ROA,SIZE,AGE,GROWTH,andLEVERAGE.VariablesareasdefinedinAppendixA.PanelA:descriptivestatisticsVariablenameTFPROASIZEAGE
GROWTHLEVERAGEOWN_PCTBODSIZENEDS
CEO_STKPAYCEO_INCENTHHI_salesHHI_assetM&A
PanelB:correlationmatrix
ROA
TFPROASIZEAGE
GROWTHLEVERAGE
BODsize
TFP
BODsizeNEDSOWN_pctCEO_STKPAYCEO_INCENT
0.090
0.300
SIZE0.3540.449
AGE0.1550.2240.351
GROWTH−0.100−0.132−0.156−0.096
LEVERAGE0.3040.2180.4430.1400.0871.000
HHI_sales0.1020.1510.0930.0360.0210.010
M&A0.0480.038−0.0100.056−0.061−0.025
OBS23062306230618621909230616452306230616941694214221422142
MEAN2.48−4.3711.0331.052.2738.3733.495.750.663.056.100.190.181.29
MEDIAN2.331.8510.7422.001.3640.7733.315.000.670.010.000.140.120.52
STDDEV2.9922.402.3324.543.3324.4023.542.530.215.0715.020.150.131.57
MIN−12.20−91.58
0.003.000.000.250.001.000.000.000.000.050.050.00
MAX14.9242.8819.40126.0021.5699.7499.8618.001.0015.5998.960.750.686.15
NEDS0.0670.304
OWN_pct0.046−0.062−0.129
CEO_STKPAY0.1090.1620.116−0.045
CEO_INCENT0.0450.060−0.016−0.0150.733
LEVERAGE,theratiooftotalliabilitiestototalassets.Thesecontrolvariablesarewinsorizedat1%and99%tominimizeimpactofoutliers.AsinNickelletal.(1997)andKokeandRenneboog(2005),weuselaggedvaluesofcontrolvariablestoreducereversecausality.
Table2providessummarystatisticsofthenumericalmeasuresofTFP,internalcorporategovernanceandfirm-levelcontrols.14ItalsoreportsthecorrelationmatrixofTFPandcontemporaneousvariables.Weobservethatfirmswithhigherproductivityarelargerfirms,morelikelytohavebetterfinancialperformance,haveexistedforalongerperiod,andusemoredebtfinancing.Wealsofindthatproductivityisnegativelycorrelatedwithgrowthopportunitiesasperceivedbytheequityinvestors.Withouttakingintoaccountotherfactorsthatinfluenceproductivity,TFPisnegativelycorrelatedwiththedegreeofproductmarketcompetition,butispositively,albeitmuchweaker,withthelevelofactivityinthemarketforcorporatecontrol.Intermsofinternalgovernancevariables,productivityispositivelycorrelatedwithmorenon-executivedirectors,largerboardsandmoreCEOstock-basedcompensation.Inaddition,ownershipconcentrationratioisnegativelycorrelatedwithboardvariables.
Withregardtofirmcharacteristics,weobservethat,thoughTFPispositiveoverthesampleperiod,financialperformanceismuchweaker(i.e.meanROAisnegative);thatmarketvalueofequityisonaveragemorethantwicethatofthefirm'sbookvalueofequity;andthatanaveragefirmwouldborrowabout38%ofitstotalassets.
4.Internalgovernance,marketdisciplineandfirmproductivity
Ourmaininterestsarewhethergoodinternalcorporategovernanceisassociatedwithhigherfirmproductivity,andwhetherexternalmarketdisciplineaffectsthisassociation.
14DefinitionsofvariablesarepresentedinAppendixA.
G.Y.Tian,G.Twite/JournalofCorporateFinance17(2011)403–417409
Table3
Differenceinmeans.Thistablepresentsthemeanofthekeyvariables:Productivity—TFP;Internalcorporategovernance—OWN_PCT,BODSIZE,NEDS,CEO_STKPAY,CEO_INCENT;Externalmarketdiscipline—HHI_sales,HHI_assets;firmlevelcontrolvariablesare:ROA,SIZE,AGE,GROWTH,andLEVERAGE.VariablesareasdefinedinAppendixA.Thefullsampleisseparatedintotwosub-samples,competitiveandnon-competitiveindustries,basedonbinaryindicatorvariableCOMPETITION,whichtakesavalueofoneforcompetitiveindustries.Theindicatorequalsoneifafirm'sHHI_salesscoreisinthebottomtercileinaparticularyear,zerootherwise.Wetestforthedifferencesinmeansbetweenthetwosub-samplesusingat-test.Differencesinmeansandtheirassociatedt-valuesarereported,with*,**and***indicatingstatisticalsignificanceat10%,5%and1%respectively.
TFP
Non-competitiveCompetitive
DifferenceinmeansT-stat
2.7342.1950.5394.33⁎⁎⁎
NEDS0.6840.6440.0403.99⁎⁎⁎ROA
Non-competitiveCompetitive
DifferenceinmeansT-stat
−3.844−3.475−0.369−0.35
BODSIZE6.0385.5460.4924.05⁎⁎⁎
SIZE11.39610.9440.4524.07⁎⁎⁎
OWN_PCT36.81438.274−1.460−1.02
CEO_STKPAY3.6083.2410.3661.62AGE34.32030.0094.2213.55⁎⁎⁎
CEO_INCENT0.0670.0640.0030.30
GROWTH2.5982.5600.0380.24
HHI_sales0.2980.0940.20445.43⁎⁎⁎
HHI_asset0.2580.1030.15533.31⁎⁎⁎LEVERAGE40.24439.1581.0870.94
4.1.Fixed-effectregressionmodels
Wenowspecifythesourcesoffirmproductivitybyexamininginternalgovernance,externalmarketdisciplineandtheirinteractioninamultipleregressionframework.SimilartoHimmelbergetal.(1999)andPhametal.(2008),weacknowledgethatordinaryleastsquaresmodelcannotsufficientlyaddresstheissueofendogeneity.Wethusconsiderthefollowingfixed-effectmodel:
ai;t=αi;t+γ1ðGOVÞi;t−1+γ2ðMKTÞi;t−1+γ3ðGOVÞi;t−1×ðMKTÞi;t−1+γ4ðControlsÞi;t−1+βt+λi+εi;t
ð3Þ
whereatisTFPwithsectorfixedeffects;tstandsforadeterministicgrowthcomponent(i.e.timeimpact),andistandsforfirmfixedeffect,whichcapturesunobservedfirmheterogeneitythatmayberelatedtobothinternalgovernanceandfirmproductivity.15Weuseagenericterm,GOV,torepresentinternalcorporategovernance,takingoneofthreevalues:ownershipconcentrationratio(CO),theproportionofnon-executivedirectorssittingontheboard(NEDS)orthelogarithmofCEOpaythatisstock-based(CEO_STKPAY).Likewise,weuseanothergenericterm,MKT,torepresentthetoughnessofexternalmarketdiscipline,asmeasuredbyHHI_salesscoresorM&Aratio.Wealsoconsidertheinteractionbetweeninternalgovernanceandthestateofexternalmarketenvironment,inwhichMKTnowtakesoneofthetwobinaryvalues:productmarketcompetition(COMPETITION),ormarketforcorporatecontrol(MKTCONTROL).Therefore,regressioncoefficientγ1capturesthebase-lineimpactofinternalgovernanceonTFP;coefficientγ3captureshowthisimpactchanges,whentheexternalmarketistough(i.e.MKTequalsone);andcoefficientγ2measuresthedirectimpactoftheexternalmarkettoughnessontheaveragelevelofTFP.4.2.Empiricalfindings
Webeginbysplittingthesamplefirmsintotwogroups–thoseinnon-competitiveindustriesandthoseincompetitiveindustries–wherecompetitivenessisdefinedusingtheindicatorvariableCOMPETITION.Table3presentsthemeansofeachofthenumericalmeasuresofTFP,internalcorporategovernanceandfirm-levelcontrols.Weobservethatfirmsinnon-competitiveindustries(i.e.greaterconcentrationofmarketpower)havehigheraverageproductivity.Thesefirmsarelargerandhavesurvivedlonger.Inaddition,theircorporateboardsarebigger,withmorenon-executivedirectors;thismaybeareflectionoftheobservationthatlargerfirmsaremorecomplextomanage(Colesetal.,2008).
Doesinternalgovernancemattertofirmproductivity?Table4presentsfixed-effectregressionresultswhenweconsideronlytheimpactofinternalcorporategovernanceonTFP,forthefullsampleandalsoseparatelyforcompetitiveandnon-competitiveindustries.16Whilethecontinuousgovernancevariablesareallinsignificantatthe5%levelforthefullsample,separatesub-
Zhou(2001)pointsoutthatfixedeffectsmodelsuchasHimmelbergetal.(1999)mightunderestimatetheassociationbetweenmanagerialownershipandfirmperformance.16Aswenoted,ananalysisofthelinkbetweenfirmproductivityandcorporategovernancedoesraiseendogeneityconcerns.Inparticular,biasesintroducedbytheeffectofunobservedfirmcharacteristicsarearealpossibility.Forexample,lowlevelsofinsiderownershipmaytheoptimalinlargefirmsthathavelowerintangibleassets,morestablecashflowsandwherethedemandformonitoringislow.Wecanfurtherarguethatthesefirmsarebetterabletoaccessexternalfinancingforpromisinginvestments,therebyimprovingproductivity.Whilewehavesoughttoaddresstheissueofunobservedheterogeneityacrossfirmsbyestimatingfixedeffectspanelregressions,thisisanincompletesolution,whichassumesstationaryrelationshipswiththeunobservablevariables.Thus,oneshouldinterprettheseresultswithsomedegreeofcaution.
15410G.Y.Tian,G.Twite/JournalofCorporateFinance17(2011)403–417
Table4
InternalCorporateGovernanceandFirmProductivity.Thistablepresentsregressionresultsofproductivity(TFP)onmeasuresofinternalcorporategovernance(OWN_PCT,NEDS,andCEO_STKPAY)andfirmlevelcontrolvariables(ROA,SIZE,AGE,GROWTH,andLEVERAGE).VariablesareasdefinedinAppendixA.Resultsarepresentedforthefullsampleandseparatelyforfirmsinnon-competitiveandcompetitiveindustries,basedonbinaryindicatorvariableCOMPETITION,whichtakesavalueofoneforcompetitiveindustries.Theindicatorequalsoneifafirm'sHHI_salesscoreisinthebottomtercileinaparticularyear,zerootherwise.Inallmodels,weincludefirmfixedeffectswithstandarderrorsrobusttoclusteringbyindividualfirmsovertime.Regressioncoefficientsandtheirassociatedt-valuesarereported,with*,**and***indicatingstatisticalsignificanceat10%,5%and1%respectively.
Non-competitive
GOV=NEDSGOV=OWN_PCTGOV=CEO_STKPAYROASIZEAGEGROWTHLEVERAGEAdjustedR2OBS
0.0010.16−0.083−1.86⁎0.0092.64⁎⁎⁎−0.043−1.75⁎0.0071.86⁎0.754553
0.0041.44−0.019−0.560.0113.57⁎⁎⁎−0.036−1.89⁎0.0041.470.699682
0.0041.45−0.028−0.950.0083.49⁎⁎⁎−0.049−2.17⁎⁎0.0072.25⁎⁎0.7651235
0.0051.10−0.247−4.97⁎⁎⁎0.0123.35⁎⁎⁎−0.059−2.460.0061.240.738553
0.0041.27−0.037−0.870.0982.77⁎⁎⁎−0.033−1.550.0051.310.786682
0.0051.76⁎−0.114−3.37⁎⁎⁎0.0114.08⁎⁎⁎−0.046−1.88⁎0.0071.80⁎0.7741235
1.0262.56⁎⁎
Competitive0.2490.79
Fullsample
0.4941.88⁎
−0.006−1.80⁎
−0.001−0.41
−0.001−0.24
0.0234.02⁎⁎⁎0.0010.20−0.011−0.240.0144.17⁎⁎⁎−0.046−1.86⁎0.0061.540.760553
−0.002−0.300.0051.43−0.065−1.65⁎0.0103.02⁎⁎⁎−0.032−1.500.0051.400.805682
0.0030.810.0041.38−0.062−1.94⁎0.0135.23⁎⁎⁎−0.052−2.19⁎⁎0.0071.94⁎0.7751235
Non-competitive
Competitive
Fullsample
Non-competitive
Competitive
Fullsample
sampleregressionsrevealquitedifferentresults.Whilegovernancedoesnotmatterwithinthecompetitiveindustries,withinthenon-competitiveindustries,bothNEDSandCEO_STKPAYhavepositiveandsignificantcoefficientsat5%level,indicatingthatmoreindependentboardsandhigherCEOstock-basedcompensationareassociatedwithbetterfirmproductivity.
Intermsoftheeconomicsignificanceofkeyvariables,thecoefficientof1.026onNEDSreportedinnon-competitiveindustriesindicatesthataone-standarddeviationincreaseinNEDSisassociatedwitha0.216(8.7percentage)increaseinTFP.Whilethe
Table5
Internalgovernance,marketcompetitivenessandfirmproductivity.Thistablepresentsregressionresultsofproductivity(TFP)onmeasuresofinternalcorporategovernance(OWN_PCT,NEDS,andCEO_STKPAY),productmarketcompetitiveness(HHI_sales,COMPETITION),theirinteractiontermsandfirmlevelcontrolvariables(ROA,SIZE,AGE,GROWTH,andLEVERAGE).VariablesareasdefinedinAppendixA.InModelA,productmarketcompetitivenessismeasuredusingcontinuousHHI_salesscores.InModelsB,CandD,competitivenessismeasuredusingbinaryindicatorCOMPETITION.Theindicatorequalsoneifafirm'sHHI_salesscoreisinthebottomtercileinaparticularyear,zerootherwise.Inallmodels,weincludefirmfixedeffectswithstandarderrorsrobusttoclusteringbyindividualfirmsovertime.Regressioncoefficientsandtheirassociatedt-valuesarereported,with*,**and***indicatingstatisticalsignificanceat10%,5%and1%respectively.
ModelA
GOV=NEDSGOV=OWN_PCTGOV=CEO_STKPAYHHI_salesCOMPETITIONGOV*COMPETITIONROASIZEAGEGROWTHLEVERAGEAdjustedR2OBS
0.0041.40−0.001−0.050.0104.34⁎⁎⁎−0.042−1.77⁎0.0083.27⁎⁎⁎0.7761235
0.8602.05⁎⁎
0.6311.74⁎−0.877−2.02⁎⁎0.0041.61−0.042−1.64⁎0.0104.90⁎⁎⁎−0.038−1.94⁎0.0041.590.7711235
−0.067−0.230.0041.010.0051.80⁎−0.074−2.48⁎⁎0.0114.85⁎⁎⁎−0.041−1.90⁎0.0051.82⁎0.7741235
0.1300.54−0.014−1.82⁎0.0041.49−0.046−1.560.0135.86⁎⁎⁎−0.037−1.71⁎0.0041.460.7811235
ModelB
0.7922.52⁎⁎
−0.006−1.80⁎
0.0122.40⁎⁎
ModelC
ModelD
coefficientof0.023onCEO_STKPAYreportedinnon-competitiveindustriesindicatesthataone-standarddeviationincreasein
G.Y.Tian,G.Twite/JournalofCorporateFinance17(2011)403–417411
Table6
Internalgovernance,takeoverthreatandfirmproductivity.Thistablepresentsregressionresultsofproductivity(TFP)onmeasuresofinternalcorporategovernance(OWN_PCT,NEDS,andCEO_STKPAY),marketforcorporatecontrol(M&AandMKTCONTROL),theirinteractiontermsandfirmlevelcontrolvariables(ROA,SIZE,AGE,GROWTH,andLEVERAGE).VariablesareasdefinedinAppendixA.InModelA,marketforcorporatecontrolismeasuredusingcontinuousM&A.InModelsB,CandD,takeoverthreatismeasuredusingbinaryindicatorMKTCONTROL.TheindicatorequalsoneifafirmoperatesinanindustrywhoseM&Ainaparticularyearisinthetoptercile,andzerootherwise.Inallmodels,weincludefirmfixedeffectswithstandarderrorsrobusttoclusteringbyindividualfirmsovertime.Regressioncoefficientsandtheirassociatedt-valuesarereported,with*,**and***indicatingstatisticalsignificanceat10%,5%and1%respectively.
ModelA
GOV=NEDSGOV=OWN_PCTGOV=CEO_STKPAYM&AMKTCONTROGOV*MKTCONTROLROASIZEAGEGROWTHLEVERAGEAdjustedR2OBS
0.0041.320.0090.300.0104.41⁎⁎⁎−0.043−2.62⁎⁎⁎0.003.40⁎⁎⁎0.7751235−2.418−1.35
0.1230.39−0.154−0.360.0041.61−0.038−1.470.0104.89⁎⁎⁎−0.038−2.70⁎⁎⁎0.0031.520.7651235
−0.024−0.110.0000.090.0051.81⁎−0.150−4.98⁎⁎⁎0.0114.86⁎⁎⁎−0.040−2.69⁎⁎⁎0.0051.84⁎0.7751235
−0.137−0.870.0201.090.0041.58−0.064−2.22⁎⁎0.0135.86⁎⁎⁎−0.039−2.64⁎⁎⁎0.0041.530.7761235
ModelB
0.4171.38
−0.004−1.21
−0.003−0.24
ModelC
ModelD
CEO_STKPAYisassociatedwitha0.117(4.7percentage)increaseinTFP.Concentratedinsiderownership,OWN_PCT,isstatisticallynegativelysignificant,albeitonlymarginally,indicatingthathigherinsiderownershipisassociatedwithpoorerfirmproductivity.Thecoefficientof-0.006onOWN_PCTindicatesthataone-standarddeviationincreaseinOWN_PCTisassociatedwitha0.142(5.7percentage)decreaseinTFP.
Focusingonfirmcharacteristics,wefindthatTFPispositivelyrelatedtofirmageand,toalesserextent,theuseofdebtfinancing.Somewhatsurprisingly,wefindthatbothfirmsizeandgrowthopportunities(asmeasuredbythemarket-to-bookratio)haveanegativeassociationwithfirmproductivity,althoughregressioncoefficientsarestatisticallysignificantat5%onlyinsomemodelspecifications.17InsimpleOLSmodelswithoutfixedeffects(nottabulatedforbrevity),productivityisalsopositivelyrelatedtoafirm'spastfinancialprofitability,laggedROA,butthisimpactbecomesinsignificantoncewecontrolforunobservedfirmeffects.
Sofar,ourresultshavesuggestedthatinternalcorporategovernanceplaysadifferentroleincompetitiveandnon-competitiveindustries:goodgovernancepromotesbetterproductionefficiencywhenthefirmfacesarelaxedexternalenvironment;however,itmatterslittlewhenthefirmoperatesinamoredisciplinedmarket.Thispointstoapotentialsubstitutioneffectbetweenthetoughnessofexternalmarketandtheeffectivenessofinternalcorporategovernance.
Doesproductmarketcompetitivenesssubstituteforinternalgovernance?Table5summarizesregressionresultsofourmainfixed-effectmodel,Eq.(3),withfourmodelspecifications.ModelAconsidersdirectimpactofexternalmarketdiscipline,usingcontinuousHHIscores,withouttakingintoaccountinternalcorporategovernance.InmodelsB,CandD,weregressTFPonmeasuresofinternalgovernance,thestateofexternalmarketcompetitiveness,COMPETITION,andtheirinteractionterms.TheindicatorvariableCOMPETITIONisusedtofacilitateinterpretation.Inallmodels,weincludefirmfixedeffectswithstandarderrorsrobusttoclusteringbyindividualfirmsovertime.
Withrespecttoexternalmarketdiscipline,byitself,ModelAresultsshowthatTFPincreasesintheHHIscores,indicatinganegativeassociationbetweenfirmproductivityandthedegreeofexternalmarketcompetition.ThisisconsistentwithTable3inthat,onaverage,firmsincompetitiveindustrieshavelowerproductivity.18Withrespecttoeconomicsignificance,thecoefficient
17ThisevidencecontrastswithPaliaandLichtenberg(1999)whofindapositiveassociationbetweenthemarket-to-bookratioandTFP.OnepotentialexplanationforthisnegativecoefficientonGROWTHisthatTFPisameasureofcurrentproductivityreflectingbothcurrentandpastinvestmentdecisions.Growthopportunities,ontheotherhand,involvefutureinvestmentschoices.Totheextentthatcurrentandfutureinvestmentdecisionsaresubstitutes,onewouldanticipateanegativecorrelationbetweengrowthopportunitiesandfirmproductivity.Togetherwithdifferencesinthesampleperiodsandvariablesdefinitions,thisexplanationmayexplainthedifferenceinresults.18Whiletheobservednegativeassociationbetweenfirmproductivityandcompetitionisinconsistentwithexpectations(Nickell,1996),possibleexplanationsforthisresultmaylieinthecompositionoursampleofAustraliafirms.Forexample,oursampleisdominatedbylarge,lowprofitabilityfirmsincompetitiveindustries,whereresourcesmaybedirectedtowardsdeferringentryratherthanimprovingproductivity(Nickell,1996),ortheselaggardfirmsarediscouragedfrominnovatingbecauseoflowpost-innovationrents(Aghionetal.,2005).Alternatively,firmsincompetitiveindustriesmayfacegreatermarketuncertaintyandmorevolatilecashflows,sotheyarelesswillingtoinvest,whichinturnharmsfirmproductivity(Nickell,1996).
412G.Y.Tian,G.Twite/JournalofCorporateFinance17(2011)403–417
Table7
Robustness—alternativemeasuresofTFP.Thistablepresentsregressionresultsofproductivity(TFP)onmeasuresofinternalcorporategovernance(OWN_PCT,NEDS,CEO_STKPAY),productmarketcompetitiveness(COMPETITION),theirinteractiontermsandfirmlevelcontrolvariables(ROA,SIZE,AGE,GROWTH,andLEVERAGE).VariablesareasdefinedinAppendixA.ModelsBandDareasdefinedinTable5.TFPismeasuredusingalternativedefinitions.WeestimateTFPusingbothvalueaddedandsalesastheoutput.Wealsoconsiderathirdinputvariable,dollaramountofmaterialscost.Forbrevity,wedonotreportthecoefficientsonfirm-levelcontrolvariables.Inallmodels,weincludefirmfixedeffectswithstandarderrorsrobusttoclusteringbyindividualfirmsovertime.Regressioncoefficientsandtheirassociatedt-valuesarereported,with*,**and***indicatingstatisticalsignificanceat10%,5%and1%respectively.
Base-lineTFP
TFPbasedonsales
TFPbasedonvalueaddedModelB0.4080.64
0.0250.880.2990.69−0.038−1.020.554778
−0.002−0.060.2670.67−0.005−0.120.452577ModelD
3-factorTFP
ModelB
GOV=NEDSGOV=CEO_STKPAYCOMPETITIONGOV*COMPETITIONAdjustedR2OBS
0.6311.74⁎−0.877−2.02⁎⁎0.7711235
0.7922.52⁎⁎
ModelDModelB0.3890.61
ModelDModelB
1.0893.06⁎⁎⁎
ModelD
0.0122.40⁎⁎0.1300.54−0.014−1.82⁎0.7811235
0.8851.33−0.837−1.98⁎0.5647780.9341.57−0.634−1.500.4655770.6031.46−1.328−2.70⁎⁎⁎0.7931235
0.0060.380.2150.75−0.010−0.480.7981235
of0.860onHHI_salesreportedinModelAindicatesthataone-standarddeviationincreaseinHHI_salesisassociatedwitha0.129(5.2percentage)increaseinTFP.
ThisaverageimpactofexternalcompetitiononTFPbecomesinsignificantonceweaddinternalgovernanceandtheinteractionbetweengovernanceandcompetition.InModelB(non-executivedirectors)andModelD(CEOstock-basedcompensation),goodgovernanceisstatisticallypositivelyrelatedtobetterfirmproductivity,whiletheinteractiontermisnegativeandsignificant.Intermsoftheeconomicsignificanceofkeyvariables,thecoefficientof0.792onNEDSreportedinModelBindicatesthataone-standarddeviationincreaseinNEDSisassociatedwitha0.166(6.7percentage)increaseinTFP.Whilethecoefficientof0.012onCEO_STKPAYreportedinModelDindicatesthataone-standarddeviationincreaseinCEO_STKPAYisassociatedwitha0.061(2.5percentage)increaseinTFP.Withrespecttotheinteractionterms(i.e.additional
Table8
Robustness—alternativemeasuresofinternalgovernance.Thistablepresentsregressionresultsofproductivity(TFP)onmeasuresofinternalcorporategovernance(BODSIZEandCEO_INCENT),productmarketcompetitiveness(COMPETITION),theirinteractiontermsandfirmlevelcontrolvariables(ROA,SIZE,AGE,GROWTH,andLEVERAGE).VariablesareasdefinedinAppendixA.Inallmodels,weincludefirmfixedeffectswithstandarderrorsrobusttoclusteringbyindividualfirmsovertime.Regressioncoefficientsandtheirassociatedt-valuesarereported,with*,**and***indicatingstatisticalsignificanceat10%,5%and1%respectively.
ModelB
GOV=BODSIZEGOV=CEO_INCENTCOMPETITIONGOV*COMPETITIONROASIZEAGEGROWTHLEVERAGEAdjustedR2OBS
0.4580.31−0.014−0.510.0041.64⁎−0.055−1.91⁎0.0104.79⁎⁎⁎−0.038−2.71⁎⁎⁎0.0031.490.7651235
0.0381.51
0.0610.130.1910.78−0.381−0.570.0041.75⁎−0.082−2.81⁎⁎⁎0.0124.97⁎⁎⁎−0.037−2.53⁎⁎0.0041.67⁎0.6801235ModelD
G.Y.Tian,G.Twite/JournalofCorporateFinance17(2011)403–417413
Table9
Quietlifevs.empirebuilding.Thistabledistinguishesbetweenthe“quietlife”and“empirebuilding”hypotheses.Inaddressingthe“quietlife”hypothesis,weconsiderLabour/Assets,theratiooflabourcostovertotalassetandR&D/Assets,theratioofR&Dinvestmentovertotalasset.While,inassessing“empirebuilding”hypotheses,weconsiderCapEx/Assets,theratioofcapitalexpenditureovertotalassetandFCF/Assets,theratiooffreecashflowovertotalasset.PanelApresentsthemeansofeachofthenumericalmeasuresofTFP,quietlifeandempirebuilding,forsub-samplesofcompetitiveandnon-competitiveindustries,wherecompetitivenessisdefinedusingtheindicatorvariableCOMPETITION.Wetestforthedifferencesinmeansbetweenthetwosub-samplesusingat-test.PanelBpresentstheresultsofthefixedeffectregressionofthemeasuresof“quietlife”(Labour/Assets,R&D/Assets)and“empirebuilding”(CapEx/Assets,FCF/Assets)oninternalcorporategovernance(NEDS),productmarketcompetitiveness(COMPETITION)andtheirinteractionterms.VariablesareasdefinedinAppendixA.Inallmodels,weincludefirmfixedeffectswithstandarderrorsrobusttoclusteringbyindividualfirmsovertime.InPanelB,regressioncoefficientsandtheirassociatedt-valuesarereported.*,**and***indicatingstatisticalsignificanceat10%,5%and1%respectively.PanelA:differenceinmeans
TFP
Non-competitive(D=0)Competitive(D=1)DifferenceinmeansT-stat
PanelB:fix-effectregression
Labour/assets
GOV=NEDSCOMPETITIONGOV*COMPETITIONAdjustedR2OBS
−0.007−0.250.1420.880.0490.260.4191235
R&D/assets−0.052−1.38−0.002−0.360.0051.000.345758
CapEx/assets0.0371.12−0.041−1.070.0210.450.5031235
FCF/assets−0.008−0.22−0.041−1.04−0.003−0.060.2801235
2.7342.1950.5394.33⁎⁎⁎
Labour/assets0.1570.282−0.125−3.39⁎⁎⁎
R&D/assets0.0040.005−0.001−0.48
CapEx/assets0.2070.2000.0070.75
FCF/assets0.0910.111−0.020−2.39⁎⁎
impactofgovernanceforfirmsincompetitiveindustries),thecoefficientof−0.877ontheinteractionofNEDSandCOMPETITIONreportedinModelBindicatesthataone-standarddeviationincreaseintheinteractiontermisassociatedwitha0.184(7.4percentage)decreaseinTFP.Whilethecoefficientof−0.014ontheinteractionofCEO_STKPAYandCOMPETITIONreportedinModelDindicatesthataone-standarddeviationincreaseintheinteractiontermisassociatedwitha0.071(2.9percentage)decreaseinTFP.Thus,externalcompetitionreducestheneedforandbenefitofinternalgovernanceinpromotingproductionefficiency.
InModelC,ownershipconcentrationisnegativelyrelatedtobetterfirmproductivity,whiletheinteractiontermispositivebutinsignificant.Thenegative,albeitweak,relationshipbetweenconcentratedinsiderownershipandfirmproductivityisconsistentwithpriorevidenceontherelationshipbetweenblock-holdingsandfirm'sfinancialperformance(Phametal.,2008)andfamilyownershipandtotalfactorproductivity(Barthetal.,2005).Theregressioncoefficientof−0.006onOWN_PCTindicatesthataone-standarddeviationincreaseinOWN_PCTisassociatedwitha0.141(5.7percentage)decreaseinTFP.
Overall,theeconomicsignificanceoftheresultspresentedinTable5isverysimilartotheeconomicsignificanceoftheresultspresentedinTable4andtheregressionresultsconcerningcontrolvariablesarealsosimilartothosereportedinTable4.
Hence,ourresultssuggestthat,overall,internalcorporategovernanceisaneffectiveinstrumenttoimprovefirm
productivity.However,internalgovernanceislesseffectivewhenafirmfacesacompetitiveproductmarket.Thereisastrongsubstitutioneffectbetweeninternalgovernanceandexternalcompetition.
Giventhatactivemarketforcorporatecontrolmayserveasanalternativewayofimposingtougherexternaldiscipline,werepeataboveanalysesusingindustry-leveltakeoveractivitiesinAustralia.Table6isstructuredinthesamefashionasTable5,replacingHHI_salesscoreswiththecontinuousmeasureoftakeoverintensitywithineachindustry,M&A,andthestateindicatorofexternalmarketdisciplinewiththeindicatorvariableMKTCONTROL.Iftakeoverthreatrepresentsaneffectivemechanismtodisciplinemanagers,wewouldexpecttofindsimilarresultsasinTable5.
Doesmarketforcorporatecontrolmattertofirmproductivity?ResultsfromTable6suggestthat,inAustralia,industry-leveltakeoveractivitiesdonothavedirectimpactonTFP.Inaddition,whenthesampleisseparatedusingindicatorvariableMKTCONTROL,neitherinternalgovernancenoritsinteractionwiththeindicatorisstatisticallysignificant.Regressioncoefficientsoffirm-levelcontrolsaresimilartothosepresentedinTable5;however,thesignificanceofgrowthopportunitieshasincreased.
Insummary,wefindthatinternalcorporategovernanceaffectsfirmproductivitydifferentlyincompetitiveandnon-competitiveindustries.Incompetitiveindustries,marketcompetitionreducestheopportunityformanagerialslackorinefficiency,andthusweakenstheeffectivenessofinternalgovernance.Ontheotherhand,innon-competitiveindustries,internalcorporate
414G.Y.Tian,G.Twite/JournalofCorporateFinance17(2011)403–417
governance–measuredeitherbyboardindependenceorCEOstock-basedcompensation–ismoreusefulandhasapositiveinfluenceonTFP.ThesefindingsareconsistentwithUSstudiesusingfinancialperformancemeasures,suchasHart(1983),Chouetal.(2008),andGiroudandMueller(2009a).
IncontrasttoUSevidenceregardingtheeffectivenessofmarketforcorporatecontrol,wedocumentthatinAustraliatakeoverthreatdoesnotinfluencefirmproductivityeitherdirectlyorindirectlyviathelinkbetweeninternalcorporategovernanceandproductivity.Thisisnotentirelysurprising.IntheUS-type“outsidersystem”,marketforcorporatecontrolcanserveasaneffectivemethodofmanagerialdiscipline.Australia,ontheotherhand,ismoreofan“insidersystem”.Dignam(2005)findthatovertheperiodof1992–2001,therewereroughly400takeoversinAustraliabutonly7%ofthemweresuccessfulhostilebids.Inoursample,theaverageindustry-leveltakeoverthreatmeasureislessthan2%.HencetheAustralianmarketischaracterizedbyaverysmallnumberofhostiletakeovers,whichinturnsuggeststhattheeffectivenessoftakeovermarketdisciplinarymechanism,whichprevailedintheU.S.,ismostlikelyabsentinAustralia.4.3.Robustnesschecks
Wemeasurefirmperformanceusingtotalfactorproductivity,TFP.OurfirstrobustnesscheckconcernsalternativedefinitionsofTFP.Forinstance,studiesonproductivitycommonlyusenumberofemployees,whileourdefinitionofTFPconsidersdollaramountofbothlabourandcapitalinputs.Ourchoiceisduetodatalimitations,aswewilllosemorethanathirdofoursampleifweadoptthisalternativemeasure.Next,weconsiderathirdinputvariable,dollaramountofmaterialscost,inestimatingEqs.(1)and(2).RegressionresultsarequalitativelythesameasthosepresentedinTables4–6.19WealsotestTFPformulasusingvalueaddedandsalesastheoutput,respectively.RegressionresultsconcerninggovernanceandmarketcompetitionbecomelesssignificantforthesetwoalternativeTFPmeasures,butthecoefficientshavesignsthatareconsistentwithourmainfindings.20RelevantrobustnesstestresultsaresummarizedinTable7.Forbrevity,wedonotreportthecoefficientsonfirm-levelcontrols,whichareconsistentwiththosereportedinTable5.
Inthemainanalysespresentedearlier,wehavechosen,oneachdimensionofinternalgovernance,onespecificmeasure.Asasecondrobustnesscheck,weconsideralternativeinternalcorporategovernancemetrics.AsanalternativetoNEDS,weconsiderBODSIZE,definedasthelogarithmofnumberofdirectorssittingonthefirm'sboard.Wepositthatsmallerboardsaremoreefficientandthusassociatedwithhigherproductivity.21AsanalternativetoCEO_STKPAY,weconsiderCEO_INCENT,percentageofCEOtotalcompensationthatisstock-based.
Table8presentsregressionresultsusingthesealternativegovernancemetrics,withexternaldisciplinebeingmeasuredbyproductmarketcompetitiveness.However,boardsize,percentageofstock-basedcompensationandtheirinteractionswiththeproductmarketcompetivenessindicatorareallstatisticallyinsignificant.
Resultsofthefollowingrobustnesstestsarenottabulatedforbrevity.TheoverallmedianHHI(sales)inoursampleis0.195,andthesescoresarebasedon4-digitGICSindustryclassification.Whenwere-calculatethesescoresusing2-digitGICS,theoverallmedianHHIdropsto0.189.TheAnti-trustDivisionoftheJusticeDepartmentintheU.S.usesHerfindahlindextomonitormarketconcentrationandtoavoidpotentialcollusion,andanindexvaluebeyond0.180isconsideredanticompetition.Toensurethatourresultsarerobusttodifferentdefinitionsofcompetitiveness,weresetthebinaryindicatorCOMPETITIONtobeoneif(a)afirmoperatesinanindustrywhoseHHIscoreisinbottomtercileinaparticularyear,(b)HHI_salessitsbelowthemedianvalue,insteadofinthebottomtercile,inaparticularyear,or(c)HHI_salesislessthanorequalto0.180.RegressionresultsareingeneralslightlyweakerbutqualitativelyconsistentwiththemainfindingsreportedinTable5.Inaddition,wealsorepeatallregressionsusingmarketpowerconcentrationmeasurebasedonassetsinsteadofsales.Ourkeymessageremains:thereisasubstitutioneffectbetweenproductmarketcompetitionandcorporategovernance.
Totieourfindingstopriorstudiesconcerningfirm'sfinancialperformance,weconsiderROAandTobin'sQasalternativedependentvariables.22Theresultsfromtheseadditionalrobustnesstestsareconsistentwithourkeyresult,inthatincompetitiveindustries,externalmarketdisciplinereducestheneedandeffectivenessoffirm-levelcorporategovernance.WithrespecttoROA,COMPETITIONhasapositiveandmarginallysignificantimpactat10%level;ourmeasuresofinternalcorporategovernancearegenerallypositivebutinsignificant,whiletheinteractiontermissignificantlynegativewheninternalgovernanceismeasuredonthedimensionofboardindependence.ResultsforTobin'sQ,proxiedasmarketvalueofequityplus
Inapreviousversion,TFPwasindeeddefinedusingallthreeinputfactors.WethankananonymousrefereeforcorrectlypointingoutthatmoststudiesonTFPconsideronlytwofactors.20Firmproductivitydefinedusingthesealternativemeasuresarehighlycorrelatedwithourbase-lineTFPmeasure.PearsoncorrelationcoefficientsofthesealternativemeasureswithTFPareallsignificant,withintherangeof0.730to0.860.21Anotherboardvariable,duality,whichhasbeenusedextensivelyintheexisting(U.S.)literatureandexpectedtohavenegativeimpactonfirmperformance,isnotsuitableforourstudy.AustraliancompanieshavealongtraditionofseparatingCEOsandboardchairmen,thusmakesthedualitymeasureextremelyskewed—morethan98%ofoursamplefirmshaveboardchairmenthatarenotcompanyCEOs.22WhenregressingROA,weconsidermodelsbothwithandwithoutlaggedROA.Likewise,withTobin'sQ,weconsidermodelsbothandwithoutthelaggedmarket-to-bookequityratio.ThecorrelationbetweenTFPandROAis0.300,andbetweenTFPandTobin'sQis−0.099.ThenegativecorrelationbetweenTFPandTobin'sQisincontrasttotheresultsreportedbyPaliaandLichtenberg(1999)whofindapositiveassociationbetweenTFPandTobin'sQ.Seefootnote12foronepotentialexplanationforthisdifferenceinresults.
19G.Y.Tian,G.Twite/JournalofCorporateFinance17(2011)403–417415
totaldebtovertotalassets,arelessconclusive.Intermsofsignsoftheregressioncoefficients,corporategovernanceispositivelyassociatedwithQ,whileCOMPETITIONandtheinteractiontermsarebothnegativelyassociatedwithQ.Theinteractiontermisonlymarginallysignificanceat10%levelwheninternalgovernanceismeasuredintermsofboardindependence.
Concerningtheimportanceofownershipstructure,priorresearchhasdocumentedacurvilinearrelationshipbetweenfinancialperformance(e.g.Tobin'sQ)andshareownershipofcorporateinsiders(e.g.Morcketal.,1988).Asalastrobustnesstest,weincludethesquaredinsiderownershipconcentrationratioinourregressionmodelsrelatedtoTables5–6.Wedonotdetectthesignificantnon-linearrelationshipbetweenTFPandinsiderequityownershipdocumentedinU.S.studies.
Lastbutcertainlynotleast,weattempttoaddressthequestionofwhichhypothesis–quietlifeorempirebuilding–ismoreconsistentwithourfindings.Unfortunately,duringoursampleperiodof2000–2005,therearenosignificantexogenoussourcesofvariationsofinternalcorporategovernanceinAustralia.InthespiritofGiroudandMueller(2010),weconsidertwoproxiesforeachhypothesisandthenregresseachoninternalgovernance,externalmarketcompetitivenessandtheirinteractionterms.Inaddressingthe“quietlife”hypothesis,weconsiderLabour/Assets,theratiooflabourcostovertotalassetsandR&D/Assets,theratioofR&Dinvestmentovertotalassets.While,inassessing“empirebuilding”hypotheses,weconsiderCapEx/Assets,theratioofcapitalexpenditureovertotalassetsandFCF/Assets,theratiooffreecashflowovertotalassets.
PanelA,Table9presentsthemeansofeachofthenumericalmeasuresofTFP,quietlifeandempirebuilding,forsub-samplesofcompetitiveandnon-competitiveindustries,wherecompetitivenessisdefinedusingtheindicatorvariableCOMPETITION.PanelB,Table9presentstheresultsofthefixedeffectregressionofthemeasuresof“quietlife”(Labour/Assets,R&D/Assets)and“empirebuilding”(CapEx/Assets,FCF/Assets)oninternalcorporategovernance,productmarketcompetitivenessandtheirinteractionterms.
Whilstthereissomeindicationthatfirmsinnon-competitiveindustriesonaverageenjoylowerlabourcostsandpossesslowerfreecashflows,neitherinternalgovernance(asmeasuredinboardindependence)norexternaldiscipline(asmeasuredbyproductmarketcompetitiveness)haveastatisticallysignificantimpactonanyoneoftheseproxies.Hence,weareunabletodisentanglethetwohypotheses.
5.Conclusionanddiscussion
Theintegrationofinternalcorporategovernance,externalmarketdisciplineandfirmproductivityhaslargelybeenoverlookedinthecurrentdebateoncorporategovernance.Priorempiricalstudies,focusinglargelyonmetricsoffinancialperformance,havefoundthatbetterinternalgovernanceisassociatedwithenhancedfirmperformance.Existingliteraturealsopointsoutthatexternalproductmarketcompetitioncouldserveasasubstituteofinternalgovernance,inthatcompetitionmitigatesagencyproblems.
UtilizingasampleofAustraliancompaniesovertheperiodof2000–2005,wetesthowcorporategovernanceinfluencesanothermetricoffirmperformance,namely,productivity.WefirstestimatetheinputsharesoflabourandcapitalcostsusingaCobb–Douglasproductionfunction,andattributetheresidualbetweenactualeconomicoutputandestimatedoutputasthemeasureofproductionefficiency,ortotalfactorproductivity(TFP).Next,weregressTFPonmeasuresofinternalcorporategovernance,externalmarketdisciplineandtheirinteractionterms,takingintoaccountfixedeffects.
Ourmainfindingssuggestthatinternalcorporategovernancecouldaffectfirmproductivity,howeverdifferentlyincompetitiveversusnon-competitiveindustries.Overall,bettergovernance–morenon-executivedirectors,smallerboardsandhigherCEOstock-basedcompensation–hasapositiveimpactonproductivity.However,whenafirmoperatesinacompetitiveindustry,thetougherproductmarketcompetitionreducesagencyproblemsand,inturn,weakenstheeffectivenessofinternalcorporategovernance.Corporategovernancematterslittletofirmproductivityduetothissubstitutioneffect.
Wefindonlyweakevidencesuggestingthattheinsiderownershipconcentrationratioservesasaneffectivegovernancechannel.Inaddition,unlikeproductmarketcompetitiveness,marketforcorporatecontrolasmeasuredbythelevelofindustry-widetakeoverthreatisfoundtohavenosignificantimpactonTFP;nordoesitservetosubstitutetheeffectivenessofinternalcorporategovernanceinpromotingbetterproductivity.
Acknowledgements
WegratefullyacknowledgethefinancialsupportunderaFaultyResearchGrantfromAustralianSchoolofBusiness(PS15941),UniversityofNewSouthWales.WethankJeffryNetter(theEditor),ananonymousreferee,JosephFan,BruceGrundy,MarkHumphery,NingGong,TomSmith,SheridanTitmanandparticipantsatthe2010AsianFinanceAssociationConferenceandtheUNSWcorporategovernancePhDseminarfortheirinsightfulsuggestions.WeareparticularlyindebtedtoRonMasulisforhishelpfulcommentsandsuggestionsthroughouttheevolutionofthispaper.RockyHeandPingYuhaveprovidedexcellentresearchassistance.Allremainingerrorsareoursalone.
416G.Y.Tian,G.Twite/JournalofCorporateFinance17(2011)403–417
AppendixA.Variabledefinition
VariableTFP
OutputLabourCapitalGOV
OWN_pct
Variablelabel
TotalfactorproductivityOutput
LabourinputCapitalinput
Variabledefinition
OperatingrevenueCostofemployees
Costofcapitalcalculatedbasedonnetproperty,plantandequipment(PP&E)
DatasourceORBISORBISORBIS
Internalcorporategovernance
OwnershipconcentrationratioPercentagecommonequityheldbyinsidersasagroup,
asreportedinWorldScope
NEDSNon-executivedirectorsPercentageofnon-executivedirectorsonthefirm'sboardBODsizeCorporateboardsizeTotalnumberofdirectorssittingontheboard
CEO_incentiveCEOstock-basedremunerationPercentageofCEO'stotalcompensationthatisstock-basedCEO_stockCEOstock-basedremunerationLogarithmofdollarvalueCEO'sstock-basedcompensationplusoneMKTStateofexternalmarketdisciplineHHI_salesHHIindex,salesHerfindahl–HirschmanIndex(4-digitGICS)basedonfirm'ssalesHHI_assetHHIindex,assetHerfindahl–HirschmanIndex(4-digitGICS)basedonfirm'stotalassetsCompetitionCompetitionindicatorIndicatorvariableforcompetitiveproductmarket.Itequalsone
ifafirmoperatesinalow-HHIindustry,zerootherwise
M&ATakeoverratioNumberoftotaltakeovertransactions(successful&failed)
dividedbynumberoftotalactivefirmswithinanindustry
MktControlTakeoveractivityindicatorIndicatorvariableforactivemarketforcorporatecontrol.Itequals
oneifafirmoperatesinahigh-M&Aindustry,zerootherwise
CONTROLFirm-levelcontrolvariablesROAReturnonassetsReturnonassets,afterdepreciationandtaxesSizeAgeGrowthLeverage
FirmsizeFirmage
GrowthopportunitiesFinancialleverage
Logarithmoffirm'stotalassetsplusone
LogarithmofnumberofyearssinceincorporationMarket-to-bookratioofcommonequityRatiooftotalliabilitiestototalassets
WORLDSCOPECONNECT4,
CONNECT4,CONNECT4,CONNECT4,
owncalculationowncalculationowncalculationowncalculation
DATANALYSIS,owncalculationDATANALYSIS,owncalculationOwncalculation
DATANALYSIS,owncalculationOwncalculation
ORBIS&DATANALYSIS,calculation
ORBIS&DATANALYSIS,calculation
ORBIS&DATANALYSIS,calculation
ORBIS&DATANALYSIS,calculation
ORBIS&DATANALYSIS,calculation
ownownownownown
AppendixB.HHIat4-digitGICSindustrylevel
4-digitGICS101015102010202020302510252025302540255030103020303035103520401040204030404045104520453050105510
Industrygroup
EnergyMaterialsCapitalgoods
Commercialservices&suppliersTransportation
Automobiles&componentsConsumerdurables&apparelConsumerservicesMediaRetailing
Food&staplesretailingFood,beverage&tobacco
Household&personalproductsHealthcareequipment&servicesPharmaceuticals&biotechBanks
DiversifiedfinancialsInsuranceRealestateITsoftware
Communicationsequipment&servicesOfficeelectronics&othersTelecommunicationservicesUtilities
2-digtGICS101520202025252525253030303535404040404545455055
Sector
EnergyMaterialsIndustrialsIndustrialsIndustrials
ConsumerdiscretionaryConsumerdiscretionaryConsumerdiscretionaryConsumerdiscretionaryConsumerdiscretionaryConsumerstaplesConsumerstaplesConsumerstaplesHealthcareHealthcareFinancialsFinancialsFinancialsFinancials
InformationtechnologyInformationtechnologyInformationtechnologyTelecommunicationUtilities
HHI_sales0.2440.0950.1210.1160.2090.1860.1090.0800.4480.0590.2280.6860.7210.1970.404n.a.n.a.n.a.n.a.0.0720.2000.3150.3520.210
HHI_asset0.1130.0920.1390.1820.1560.2170.1480.0820.4870.1010.1590.6050.6230.1630.258n.a.n.a.n.a.n.a.0.0930.1610.2590.3430.116
G.Y.Tian,G.Twite/JournalofCorporateFinance17(2011)403–417417
References
Aggarwal,R.,Samwick,A.,1999.Executivecompensation,strategiccompetition,andrelativeperformanceevaluation:theoryandevidence.J.Finance.54,
1999–2043.
Aghion,P.,Bloom,N.,Blundell,R.,Griffith,R.,Howitt,P.,2005.Competitionandinnovation:aninverted-Urelationship.Q.J.Economics.120,701–728.Alchian,A.,1950.Uncertainty,evolutionandeconomictheory.J.Polit.Economy.58,211–221.
Allen,F.,Gale,D.,2000.Corporategovernanceandcompetition.In:Vives,X.(Ed.),CorporateGovernance:TheoreticalandEmpiricalPerspectives.Cambridge
UniversityPress,Cambridge,pp.23–94.
Barth,E.,Gulbrandsen,T.,Schone,P.,2005.Familyownershipandproductivity:theroleofowner–manager.J.Corp.Finance.11,107–127.Bebchuk,L.A.,Cohen,A.,Ferrell,A.,2009.Whatmattersincorporategovernance?Rev.Financ.Studies.22,783–827.
Bertrand,M.,Mullainathan,S.,2003.Enjoyingthequietlife?Corporategovernanceandmanagerialpreferences.J.Polit.Economy.111,1043–1075.Bhagat,S.,Bolton,B.J.,2008.Corporategovernanceandfirmperformance.J.Corp.Finance.14,257–273.
Borokhovich,K.A.,Parrino,R.,Trapani,T.,1996.OutsidedirectorsandCEOselection.J.Financ.Quant.Anal.31,337–355.Bulan,L.,Sanyal,P.,Yan,Z.,2007.CEOIncentivesandFirmProductivity,Workingpaper.BrandeisUniversity.
Chou,W.,Ng,L.,Wang,Q.,2008.ProductMarketCompetitionandCorporateGovernance,Workingpaper.GeorgiaInstituteofTechnology.Coles,J.L.,Daniel,N.D.,Naveen,L.,2008.Boards:doesonesizefitall?J.Financ.Economics.87,329–356.
Conyon,M.,Peck,S.,1998.Boardsizeandcorporateperformance:evidencefromEuropeancountries.Eur.J.Finance.4,291–304.
Core,J.E.,Holthausen,R.W.,Larcker,D.F.,1999.Corporategovernance,chiefexecutiveofficercompensation,andfirmperformance.J.Financ.Economics.51,
371–406.
Dignam,A.,2005.Thetakeoverpanel,themarketefficiencyprincipleandthemarketforcorporatecontrol—anempiricalstudy.CompanySecuritiesLawJournal.
23,58–64.
Dignma,A.,Galanis,M.,2004.Australiainside-out:thecorporategovernancesystemoftheAustralianlistedmarket.MelbourneUniv.LawReview.28,623–653.Giroud,X.,Mueller,H.M.,2009.CorporateGovernance,ProductMarketCompetition,andEquityPrices.CEPRDiscussionPaperNo.6974.Giroud,X.,Mueller,H.M.,2010.Doescorporategovernancematterincompetitiveindustries?J.Financ.Economics.95,312–331.Gompers,P.,Ishii,J.,Metrick,A.,2003.Corporategovernanceandequityprices.Q.J.Economics.118,107–155.Hart,O.D.,1983.Themarketmechanismasanincentivescheme.BellJ.Economics.14,366–382.
Hartzell,J.C.,Starks,L.,2003.Institutionalinvestorsandexecutivecompensation.J.Finance.58l,2351–2374.
Hill,C.W.,Snell,S.A.,1989.Effectsofownershipstructureandcontroloncorporateproductivity.Acad.Manage.J.32,25–46.
Himmelberg,C.P.,Hubbard,R.G.,Palia,D.,1999.Understandingthedeterminantsofmanagerialownershipandthelinkbetweenownershipandperformance.
J.Financ.Economics.53,353–384.
Hulten,C.R.,2000.TotalFactorProductivity:aShortBiography.NBERWorkingPaper7471.
Jensen,M.C.,1993.Themodernindustrialrevolution,exit,andthefailureofinternalcontrolsystems.J.Finance.48,831–880.Jensen,M.C.,Murphy,K.J.,1990.Performancepayandtop-managementincentives.J.Polit.Economy.98,225–264.Kim,M.,Maksimovic,V.,1990.Debtandinputmisallocation.J.Finance.45,795–816.
Koke,J.,Renneboog,L.,2005.Docorporatecontrolandproductmarketcompetitionleadtostrongerproductivitygrowth?Evidencefrommarket-orientedand
blockholder-basedgovernanceregimes.J.LawEconomics.48,475–516.
Krugman,P.,1990.TheAgeofDiminishedExpectations:theUSEconomicPoliciesinthe1990s.MITPress,Massachusetts.LaPorta,R.,Lopez-de-Silanes,F.,Shleifer,A.,1999.Corporateownershiparoundtheworld.J.Finance.54,471–517.
Lamba,A.,Stapledon,G.,2003.TheDeterminantsofCorporateOwnershipStructure:AustralianEvidence,Workingpaper.UniversityofMelbourne.
Levin,R.,Cohen,W.,Mowery,D.,1985.R&DAppropriability,opportunityandmarketstructure:newevidenceonsomeSchumpeterianhypotheses.Am.Econ.Rev.
Proceedings.75,20–24.
Lichtenberg,F.,Siegel,D.,1987.Productivityandchangesinownershipofmanufacturingplants.In:Lichtenberg,F.,Siegel,D.,Jorgenson,D.,Mansfield,E.(Eds.),
SpecialIssueonMicroeconomics.BrookingInstitution,Washington,pp.643–683.
Maksimovic,V.,Phillips,G.,1996.EfficiencyofBankruptFirmsandIndustryConditions:TheoryandEvidence.CESDiscussionPaper100248.
Martikainen,M.,Nikkinen,J.,Vahamaa,S.,2009.Productionfunctionsandproductivityoffamilyfirms:evidencefromtheS&P500.Q.Rev.Econ.Finance49,
295–307.
Masulis,R.W.,Wang,C.,Xie,F.,2007.Corporategovernanceandacquirerreturns.J.Finance.62,1851–1889.
McConnell,J.,Servaes,H.,1990.Additionalevidenceonequityownershipandcorporatevalue.J.Financ.Economics.27,595–612.
Morck,R.K.,Shleifer,A.,Vishny,R.W.,1988.Managementownershipandmarketvaluation:anempiricalanalysis.J.Financ.Economics.20,293–315.Murphy,K.J.,1999.Executivecompensation.In:Ashenfelter,O.,Layard,R.(Eds.),HandbookofLaborEconomics.ElsevierScienceB.V,pp.2485–2563.Nickell,S.,1996.Competitionandcorporateperformance.J.Polit.Economy.104,724–746.
Nickell,S.,Nicolitsas,D.,Dryden,N.,1997.Whatmakesfirmsperformwell?Eur.Econ.Review.41,783–796.
Palia,D.,Lichtenberg,F.,1999.Managerialownershipandfirmperformance:are-examinationusingproductivitymeasurement.J.Corp.Finance5,323–339.Pham,P.K.,Suchard,J.A.,Zein,J.,2008.CorporateGovernanceAndAlternativePerformanceMeasures:EvidencefromAustralianFirms,Workingpaper.University
ofNewSouthWales.
Shleifer,A.,Vishny,R.W.,1986.Largeshareholdersandcorporatecontrol.J.Polit.Economy.94,461–488.Shleifer,A.,Vishny,R.W.,1997.Asurveyofcorporategovernance.J.Finance.52,737–783.Stigler,G.,1958.Theeconomicsofscale.J.LawEconomics.1,54–71.
Yermack,D.,1996.Highermarketvaluationofacompanywithasmallboardofdirectors.J.Financ.Economics.40,185–211.
Zhou,X.,2001.Understandingthedeterminantsofmanagerialownershipandthelinkbetweenownershipandperformance:comment.J.Financ.Economics.62,
559–571.
因篇幅问题不能全部显示,请点此查看更多更全内容